학술논문
부유한 수공업자와 가난한 상인 - 오스만 길드의 ‘평등주의’에 대한 재검토
이용수 162
- 영문명
- Rich Artisans and Poor Merchants: A Critical Look at the Supposed Egalitarianism in Ottoman Guilds
- 발행기관
- 한국중동학회
- 저자명
- 李恩廷(Yi Eun-Jeong)
- 간행물 정보
- 『한국중동학회논총』제27권 제2호, 203~233쪽, 전체 31쪽
- 주제분류
- 사회과학 > 지역학
- 파일형태
- 발행일자
- 2007.02.28
6,520원
구매일시로부터 72시간 이내에 다운로드 가능합니다.
이 학술논문 정보는 (주)교보문고와 각 발행기관 사이에 저작물 이용 계약이 체결된 것으로, 교보문고를 통해 제공되고 있습니다.
국문 초록
영문 초록
Although some Ottoman craft guilds did have a quasi-egalitarian streak, we may not consider it a product simply of sufi-futuwwa ethics. Some of the futuwwah literature explicitly accommodates both artisans and merchants, and the futuwwah mindset, given its flexibility and amorphousness, could often have tolerated the relatively rich, as long as they provided charity and showed sympathy toward their less fortunate colleagues. Likewise, we find craft-guilds less adamantly egalitarian than we have thought. There is evidence that quite different scales of businesses could coexist in the same guild or trade, from the shop sales/rent documents, a waqfdocument, and tereke documents as we have seen in this paper.
In the light of seventeenth-century Istanbul court records, most guilds seem to have been self-organized and self-defined professional associations whose purpose was to promote common interests. Therefore, their internal arrangements could vary greatly depending on their situations and needs, and egalitarianism may or may not have featured prominently in such arrangements. What guilds were about was to uphold the advantageous order in and around their trade. What they wanted was to guard their established interests and not necessarily to curb the rich, as long as the latter did not disrupt the order in their system. The leaders of the guilds must have been relatively well-off, being able to give some material service to other members and get good reputation in return. There obviously was wider differentiation of wealth within a guild, and guildsmen may not necessarily have considered this problematic, as it could have been beneficial to have some rich members in their group.
In addition, we may need to re-consider the boundary between artisans and merchants. The line between the two categories is blurred not only by rich artisans but also by poor local retailers whose behavior, outlook, and even organization was similar to craft guilds. There were quite different levels of wealth on both sides of artisans and merchants, so that those who were at the high and low extremes may not necessarily have felt that they had much in common or belonged together as artisans or merchants. Meanwhile, artisans and merchants were in close relationship as the latter brought raw materials for the former and often provided credits. Business partnerships crossing the imaginary boundary between artisans on one side and merchants on the other must have been common. In addition, some vague terms that could be applied to both artisans and merchants, such as ehl-i suk and ?elebi (designating the prominent ones among them) seem to indicate that the two classes could merge to some extent in the eyes of the contemporaries.
Now that it is clear that some artisan groups could tolerate economic differentiation in their guilds and that some individuals could become and remain relatively wealthy within the guild system, we should note significant exceptions to the stereotype of the Ottoman artisans as poor, egalitarian small producers. To further examine artisans" economic status and the whole gamut of their relations to diverse group of merchants would be crucial in reconstructing the fabric of Ottoman urban society and the dynamics therein.
In the light of seventeenth-century Istanbul court records, most guilds seem to have been self-organized and self-defined professional associations whose purpose was to promote common interests. Therefore, their internal arrangements could vary greatly depending on their situations and needs, and egalitarianism may or may not have featured prominently in such arrangements. What guilds were about was to uphold the advantageous order in and around their trade. What they wanted was to guard their established interests and not necessarily to curb the rich, as long as the latter did not disrupt the order in their system. The leaders of the guilds must have been relatively well-off, being able to give some material service to other members and get good reputation in return. There obviously was wider differentiation of wealth within a guild, and guildsmen may not necessarily have considered this problematic, as it could have been beneficial to have some rich members in their group.
In addition, we may need to re-consider the boundary between artisans and merchants. The line between the two categories is blurred not only by rich artisans but also by poor local retailers whose behavior, outlook, and even organization was similar to craft guilds. There were quite different levels of wealth on both sides of artisans and merchants, so that those who were at the high and low extremes may not necessarily have felt that they had much in common or belonged together as artisans or merchants. Meanwhile, artisans and merchants were in close relationship as the latter brought raw materials for the former and often provided credits. Business partnerships crossing the imaginary boundary between artisans on one side and merchants on the other must have been common. In addition, some vague terms that could be applied to both artisans and merchants, such as ehl-i suk and ?elebi (designating the prominent ones among them) seem to indicate that the two classes could merge to some extent in the eyes of the contemporaries.
Now that it is clear that some artisan groups could tolerate economic differentiation in their guilds and that some individuals could become and remain relatively wealthy within the guild system, we should note significant exceptions to the stereotype of the Ottoman artisans as poor, egalitarian small producers. To further examine artisans" economic status and the whole gamut of their relations to diverse group of merchants would be crucial in reconstructing the fabric of Ottoman urban society and the dynamics therein.
목차
Ⅰ. 서론
Ⅱ. 푸투와(futuwwa)에 기반을 둔 평등주의의 문제
Ⅲ. 길드 회원들의 행동에서 평등주의적으로 보이는 요소들
Ⅳ. 길드 회원 사이의 빈부격차의 정도
Ⅴ. 수공업자 및 서비스업자의 상인과의 경계
Ⅵ. 결론
참고문헌
Ⅱ. 푸투와(futuwwa)에 기반을 둔 평등주의의 문제
Ⅲ. 길드 회원들의 행동에서 평등주의적으로 보이는 요소들
Ⅳ. 길드 회원 사이의 빈부격차의 정도
Ⅴ. 수공업자 및 서비스업자의 상인과의 경계
Ⅵ. 결론
참고문헌
해당간행물 수록 논문
- 부유한 수공업자와 가난한 상인 - 오스만 길드의 ‘평등주의’에 대한 재검토
- 한국중동학회 정관 외
- 이슬람 지하드의 의미와 그 현대적 적용
- 오사마 빈 라덴의 담화에 나타난 언어적 특징과 수사적 전략에 관한 고찰
- 레바논 무슬림의 일부다처 현상에 관한 연구
- 제국주의로 본 미국의 중동정책 - 클린턴과 조지 W. 부시의 중동정책을 중심으로
- A Study on Images of Korea in the Arab
- 시리아 소수집단 알라위파(Alawites)의 집권과 국민통합 정책에 대한 연구
- 알카에다와 메가 테러리즘환경 분석 - 알카에다 조직의 메가 테러리즘 전략과 사례분석
참고문헌
교보eBook 첫 방문을 환영 합니다!
신규가입 혜택 지급이 완료 되었습니다.
바로 사용 가능한 교보e캐시 1,000원 (유효기간 7일)
지금 바로 교보eBook의 다양한 콘텐츠를 이용해 보세요!